Barry Haworth
University of Louisville
Department of Economics
Economics 201


The Consumer Equilibrium: Part 2



So how many slices of pizza will Jane buy in this situation? If Jane’s decision is best made by using marginal analysis, then we must consider how each individual slice of pizza is valued by Jane and then compare that value to the pizza’s cost. Let’s assume Jane is an honest person and that she has no reason to lie when asked how much she’d be willing to pay for each slice of pizza (this is obviously not a realistic assumption if the question’s being asked by the seller). Our forthcoming analysis is simple, we’ll ask a pair of questions before Jane purchases each slice of pizza. Question #1 is directed at Jane "How much would you be willing to pay for this slice?" Question #2 is something we’ll ask ourselves, "If that slice is $2, then will Jane buy it?"

How much is that first slice worth? Jane says she’s quite hungry and would really like some pizza, so she’d be willing to pay up to $4 for that slice. Because the slice only costs her $2, she’ll obviously want to buy it. After eating the first slice of pizza, Jane considers a second. How much is the second slice worth? Jane’s still hungry, but obviously not as hungry as before the first slice. Consequently, that second slice isn’t worth as much to Jane. Her answer is that she’d be willing to pay up to $3 for a second slice of pizza. Will she buy it? Again, as before, a person will always purchase something if they know they’ll derive greater gain from that purchase than they give up in cost. Jane will buy a second slice of pizza.

After two slices of pizza, Jane’s starting to feel a little full. She’d only be willing to pay $2 for a third slice. Compared with the $2 cost, however, our logic above leads us to conclude that she’d still buy a third slice of pizza. The fourth slice of pizza is another story. Jane could eat a fourth slice, but it would leave her feeling very full, something she doesn’t like to do very often. How much would she be willing to pay for that fourth slice? She replies that she’d be willing to pay 50 cents for it, but no more. Will she buy four slices of pizza? No, Jane wouldn’t be behaving very rationally if she purchased a $2 slice of pizza that she only thought was worth 50 cents. Let's record this information in a table (below).

Slice
Benefit
Cost
Net Benefit
1st
$4
$2
$2
2nd
$3
$2
$1
3rd
$2
$2
$0
4th
50¢
$2
-$1.50

Why does Jane buy 3 slices of pizza and not 4 slices? The obvious answer is that as long as Jane doesn't experience any reductions in net benefit, she'll continue buying pizza slices. This implies that she'll continuing purchasing until she buys 3 slices, but will stop before the fourth slice because that fourth slice makes her worse off.

Looking at the table, we can make a couple additional, more formal points. Note first that the benefit from each successive slice of pizza gets less and less. That is, note that the marginal benefit associated with each slice is decreasing. This corresponds with what we call the Law of Diminishing Marginal Utility (or returns). Diminishing marginal returns does not imply that Jane should stop buying pizza slices at any specific point, but does imply that this stopping point will eventually occur since Jane consumes until the marginal benefit and marginal cost are equal.

Another point concerns the net benefit derived from each slice. Although Jane is willing to pay $4 for the first slice of pizza, she only has to pay $2. In a sense, Jane has saved money. We call this type of saving Consumer Surplus, and it represents the difference between the most one is willing to pay and what one actually does pay (summed up for all units purchased). The more consumer surplus Jane acquires, the more benefit she derives from her consumption.



By graphing this information, it’s possible to see all of this framed in a slightly different manner. The benefit from each slice is measured in terms of the willingness to pay for each slice, and the cost of each slice is measured in terms of the price of each slice. This dollar amount per slice is represented by movement up the vertical axis. The horizontal axis identifies the number of the slice we’re looking at (e.g. whether it’s the second or third slice) and indicates the number of slices purchased.

On the graph below, the blue line connects the points associated with Jane’s willingness to pay for each slice. We call this line the marginal benefit curve. The red line represents the cost of each slice. We call this line the marginal cost curve.

The intersection of these lines occurs at the point where the price of each slice of pizza equals what Jane’s willing to pay for that slice. That is, the intersection occurs where Jane’s marginal benefit curve intersects her marginal cost curve. Jane consumes where her marginal benefit equals her marginal cost (i.e. where MB = MC). The negative slope of the marginal benefit curve demonstrates what we refered to earlier as the Law of Diminishing Marginal Utility.

The graph also illustrates the concept of consumer surplus. If Jane consumes 1 slice, then she receives $2 in net benefit. If Jane consumes two slices, she receives $3 in overall net benefit. Jane stops purchasing pizza at the third slice, where the net benefit is zero. By summing up her net benefit, we get an approximation of the area below the marginal benefit curve, but above the marginal cost (price) curve. This area is Jane's consumer surplus.



Note that although we can use marginal analysis to find an answer to the question "how much should Jane buy", we don’t necessarily know how much overall net benefit Jane derives from that consumption. Marginal analysis allows one to determine how much of an activity will occur, but doesn't necessarily tell us whether the net benefit derived from that activity will be positive or negative.